You are here

Collective intelligence and the common good

Aug 06,2024 - Last updated at Aug 06,2024

LONDON — Collective intelligence is becoming a catchphrase meant to capture the essence of the knowledge economy, where multitudes of people collaborate on difficult challenges, with each bringing something different to the table. The result is continuous experimentation and innovation, leading to great discoveries. And with the proliferation of artificial intelligence, the participants in this process may not even be human. Isn’t that a nice thought?

As compelling as this description may be, our romantic narrative of how discovery occurs obscures the terms of collaboration. Who is participating? Who is actually creating value? And how are the rewards being distributed? Those profiting from the status quo would prefer that we not ask.

Yet these are pertinent questions, because many of those who contribute to innovation are often overlooked. Labor regularly gets dismissed, as does the state. I called attention to this in my 2013 book, The Entrepreneurial State, which examined the tendency to see the private sector as a value-creating risk taker, and the state as merely a de-risker or impediment to value creation. This traditional framing ignores the state’s role in funding innovations like the mRNA COVID-19 vaccines, which were supported by some $31.9 billion in US public investment.

Unless we rethink these narratives about value creation, innovation will continue to benefit only shareholders, rather than all stakeholders — from workers to the communities where businesses operate. For “stakeholder value” to be more than a corporate-governance gimmick, we must not only recognise that value is created collectively, but also ensure that the rewards are shared more broadly across all creators.

For example, profits should be reinvested in the real economy, rather than being put toward share buybacks, which totaled $6.3 trillion between 2010 and 2019. Making matters worse, under the current system, tax havens collectively cost governments $500-$600 billion per year in lost corporate-tax revenue, and the magnitude is even greater when considering wealthy individuals as well. This avoidance prevents all stakeholders from reaping the rewards of collective intelligence and collaboration.

To fix the problem, one must understand how collective intelligence leads to value creation in the first place. Collaboration entails knowledge sharing, but if we privatise knowledge and research, this becomes more difficult. It makes sense to have intellectual-property rights to incentivise investment and innovation. But if those rights are too broad, they can be abused for strategic reasons. If they are too strong, technologies become harder to access or license. And if they are too concentrated upstream, with basic research tools remaining privatised, discovery and innovation will suffer.

As contracts that grant 17 years of monopoly profits to a business (in the US case), patents should be negotiated and governed with these considerations in mind. Rather than serving merely as a tool to fix information asymmetries — a type of market failure — they must shape the broader knowledge-governance system.

How might a genuine collective-intelligence framework alter the structure of patents (in medicine, for example) and other contracts that determine how knowledge is created and shared? As I have argued previously, the objective in all our collective economic activity should be to serve the common good. This is the principle that should guide our thinking about collaboration and the distribution of rewards.

Whenever wealth is created socially, many partners in the collaborative process will have taken a risk with no guarantee of a return. As powerful as collective intelligence may be, failure is always a possibility. But when success does come, the returns ought to be shared as widely as the risks were. Otherwise, the arrangement is more parasitic than symbiotic.

A mutualistic innovation ecosystem would ensure that the monetary rewards are shared (such as through profit-sharing or equity schemes); or that the knowledge is shared; or that the prices of the final products (like medicines) reflect the collective investment that went into them. This is rarely the case, not only with medicines, but also in digital technologies and renewable energy. For example, many renewable-energy companies benefit from generous tax schemes, which means the public is supporting their profit margins without partaking in the gains.

In the digital domain, a common-good approach would ensure that new technologies like AI are creating opportunities for public value creation. Diversity is essential here, because innovation benefits from different perspectives. That is why Apple brought in musicians, designers, and artists to help design its products. The original moon landing succeeded because different departments in NASA worked together horizontally, rather than vertically.

Collective intelligence is not groupthink, which merely creates siloes and introduces unnecessary risks. I warned in a previous commentary that AI-powered systems are reproducing unfair social biases. Without better oversight, algorithms that are supposed to help the public sector manage welfare benefits may discriminate against needy households.

Finally, voice matters, because finding durable solutions to our biggest problems increasingly requires contestation and negotiation. Too often, policy outcomes are distorted by those with the loudest voice, those who can afford the best lawyers, and those with the most power to influence the direction and define the purpose of innovation.

Is digital data collection and analysis supposed to make a few people rich, or should it liberate us, such as by helping to make housing more available and affordable? Given that technology consumers often provide their personal data to corporations for free — even amid growing concerns about data privacy — shouldn’t they have a voice in how that technology is developed?

Or consider climate change. Indigenous communities disproportionately bear the consequences of a problem created by others. Should they not have a prominent seat at the table when the topic of the Amazon and how to protect it is discussed? In the recent negotiations for a global pandemic treaty, lower-income countries were asked to share pathogen data without any guarantee that they will have access to the resulting products. These stakeholders need to have a say in determining the future of pharmaceutical innovation, as well as how its rewards are distributed.

The reality of how value is created and distributed through collaborative innovation has been woefully obscured. By debunking the myth that value is created by the private sector, and that the state is, at best, a de-risker and crisis manager, we can develop a proper understanding of how innovation works. If we want to leverage the power of collective intelligence, we will need to adopt a common-good framework. Given the scale of today’s global challenges, we will need to do it fast.

Mariana Mazzucato, professor in the Economics of Innovation and Public Value at University College London, is founding director of the UCL Institute for Innovation and Public Purpose and a co-chair of the Global Commission on the Economics of Water. She was chair of the World Health Organisation’s Council on the Economics of Health For All. She is the author of “The Value of Everything: Making and Taking in the Global Economy” (Penguin Books, 2019), “Mission Economy: A Moonshot Guide to Changing Capitalism” (Penguin Books, 2022), and, most recently, “The Big Con: How the Consulting Industry Weakens Our Businesses, Infantilises Our Governments and Warps Our Economies” (Penguin Press, 2023). A tenth anniversary edition of her book “The Entrepreneurial State: Debunking Public vs Private Sector Myths” was published by Penguin in September.

up
17 users have voted.

Add new comment

CAPTCHA
This question is for testing whether or not you are a human visitor and to prevent automated spam submissions.
PDF